Hayek Vs Keynes Compare And Contrast Essay

Keynes Hayek: The Clash That Defined Modern Economics, by Nicholas Wapshott, W.W. Norton & Co., 382 pages, $28.95

British journalist Nicholas Wapshott’s new book, Keynes Hayek: The Clash That Defined Modern Economics is about a heated debate, eight decades past, between two of the most influential economists in modern history. That debate, which took place in the midst of the Great Depression, concerned the causes and cures of business cycle downturns. 

The book comes out at a propitious time. The ongoing economic crisis raises many of the same questions that fueled the intellectual duel between the British-born liberal lion John Maynard Keynes and F.A. Hayek, his free market Austrian friend and opponent. The confluence between subject matter and current events surely helped Wapshott sell his book to a publisher and likely will sell many copies to readers. But potential buyers should be aware that the book says nothing about how the economic dispute between Keynes and Hayek might apply to today’s economic situation. This omission proves fatal.

Wapshott does not ignore the present in favor of the distant past, although the bulk of the book’s narrative is set in the 1930s. But he seems to think his subjects’ contemporary relevance is best reduced to the big-picture conflict between government intervention (Keynes) and free markets (Hayek). Wapshott focuses on the disagreements the two had over political philosophy and practice rather than the technical specifics of their economics. Those political disagreements are important, but they arose from crucial differences in economic theory. 

For example, Keynes believed that intelligent, well-meaning planners manipulating economic aggregates such as demand and employment can bring about a happy end to business cycles. Hayek, by contrast, insisted that individual decisions and imbalances between specific prices and demand, or interest rates and specific plans for long-term productive projects, are where the economic action is. 

Modern Keynesians tend to sniff at the notion that their man and Hayek were equal participants in the “clash that defined modern economics.” They note that Hayek did not wield a similarly huge influence on modern macroeconomics, and they are right in the sense that the Austrian questioned the value of macroeconomics as an intellectual project in the first place.

At its root the Keynes/Hayek clash concerned alternate theories about how business cycles work. Wapshott does a workmanlike job walking readers through the lectures, books, articles, reviews, rebuttals, and counter-rebuttals that made up the bulk of their dispute. That is the book’s greatest value, and it’s the most thorough and lengthy such discussion available in the lay literature. 

Before the two men began feuding, Keynes was already a hero to the rising generation of economists at Cambridge, but his ideas were considered somewhat heretical by the dons of the London School of Economics. The LSE’s Lionel Robbins imported Hayek, a monetary/business cycle theorist and disciple of Ludwig von Mises, to represent a counter-Keynesian perspective. (Robbins and Keynes had feuded as members of a government commission, where Robbins refused to sign on to Keynes’ prescriptions for public works spending and tariffs as a solution to the Depression.) The Austrians thought free markets tended toward a workable equilibrium that reflected people’s desires and choices; the new Keynesian ideas posited that free markets sometimes guided economies into ditches from which only concerted government action could pull them out. 

This book is about nothing if not economic theory and history; the personalities simply aren’t that gripping, despite slightly interesting scattered details about Hayek’s marital troubles and the torrid affairs between Keynes’ disciples. Yet Wapshott somehow never spends more than a sentence or two at a time on complicated economic ideas. He devotes far more space to discussing the feuding economists’ intemperate tone than he does to explaining what they meant. Readers who don’t already have a basic understanding of Hayekian and Keynesian economics will get little help here.

The book is riddled with errors of judgment, especially about Hayek’s position. Wapshott thinks that Austrian theory is “mechanistic” and based on a belief that the “free market was virtuous.” In fact, Hayek’s notion was that markets were highly organic, especially compared to Keynes’ vision of manipulating economies like machinery, and Hayek’s Austrian perspective was studiedly and deliberately value-free in its economic analysis. While Austrians tend to think free markets redound to the greatest benefit of the greatest number, that conclusion arose from their scientific understanding of how the world worked, not a moral judgment about how it should be.

Wapshott thinks the Misesian critique of socialism was that prices “were made redundant,” when what Mises actually said about socialism is that it made prices, and the information we get from prices, impossible. Wapshott thinks Hayek’s understanding of the function served by prices was not about the spread and coordination of decentralized information and knowledge (which it was) but rather about freedom. At the end of the book, where you’d expect Hayek’s economic views about business cycles to be central to the discussion, Wapshott forgets them entirely in favor of his politics.

But the Keynes/Hayek argument was more complex than just the political question of government vs. markets. It was about complicated notions of price adjustment, especially the vital question of price adjustments for labor. In a 1930s context of very powerful unions, Keynes thought it was politically impossible to achieve the nominal wage reductions necessary to clear the market for labor—that is, to let wages fall so that hiring would be cheaper and unemployment thereby reduced. He instead promoted inflation as a means to trick labor into taking lower real wages. 

Wapshott seems to want us to take Keynes’ side on this. He writes sentences like, “Keynes believed that the chronic unemployment endured by Britain and America in the 1920s and 1930s was evidence that the full employment equilibrium was a fallacy,” without mentioning prices or wages. The point from Hayek’s side is that no equilibrium is possible when prices don’t or can’t adjust. In neither country did wages—the price of labor—adjust downward in order to increase the demand for labor—that is, employment.

Unemployment was understandably one of the great battlegrounds of the Keynes/Hayek feud. In a business cycle bust, did unemployment have to be cured by government manipulation of aggregate demand—by spending any way, any how, as Keynes advocated? Keynes thought that if you have idle people and capital goods, you should get them working again by any means available, even if the projects prove inflationary or produce nothing that anyone wants (such as holes by the side of the road). 

From Hayek’s perspective, booms and busts were caused by unnatural credit creation, setting in motion productive processes (say, home building) that end up not paying off in the end, given people’s real desire for future goods vs. present ones. Under normal circumstances, those desires would tend toward equilibrium via adjustments in interest rates. But interest rates are skewed by artificial credit creation. While the additional credit has short-term stimulative effects (booms), in the long run a structure of production that does not match actual saved capital will collapse, leading to damaging busts.

Keynes’ most famous quip (although he said it before his Hayek fight and in a different context) applied to Hayek’s worries about the long-run effects of inflationary attempts to put the consumption cart before the production horse. “In the long run,” Keynes said, “we are all dead.” 

Hayek thought the long run might come quicker than Keynesians believed. In his 1941 book Pure Theory of Capital, the Austrian quoted Keynes’ famous line, adding, “I fear that these believers in [that principle] may get what they have bargained for sooner than they wish.” Hayekians would argue that our current economic crisis is an example of living in Keynes’ “long run”—that inflationary credit expansion and high levels of government spending have led to a bust and a debt crisis that we can’t handle. While Keynes himself thought government should spend borrowed money only during recessions, his disciples in government observe no such restriction.

Partly because he shifted from economics to political philosophy in the second half of his career, Hayek is often treated merely as a small-government polemicist. (Wapshott, trying to complicate this view, erroneously reports that Hayek believed in universal government-provided health care.) It’s a shame that a book centered on the years of Hayek’s greatest and most influential work as an economist only cements this incomplete reputation.

 

By Jonathan Mariano
Three of the most influential economists include John Maynard Keynes, Milton Friedman, and F.A. Hayek. Keynes and Friedman are typically viewed as opposing, rather than supporting each others views. Hayek often gets overlooked, although is becoming prominent once again, as of the last boom and bust. It’s interesting to note the overlap and differences between the three economists.

Keynes vs. (Friedman + Hayek) on Markets
When it comes to markets, Keynes suggests interventionism from the government, and Friedman + Hayek usually suggest free markets with little, if any government involvement.

(Keynes vs. Hayek) vs. Friedman on Monetary Policy
Friedman suggests that monetary policy, controlling the money supply, can help smooth out recessions. On the other hand, Keynes suggests monetary policy plays little role in stimulating the economy and aggregate demand. Rather, Keynes’ solution is spending by government. Hayek is adamantly opposed to monetary policy, as he thinks its implementation is what causes boom-bust cycles in the first place.

Keynes vs. (Friedman vs. Hayek) on Fiscal Policy
Keynes suggests fiscal policy to help prime the pump to recovery after a recession, where government stimulus packages prop up the economy. Friedman and Hayek oppose such intervention on the basis of interfering with the market process. Hayek takes a stronger stance against any such intervention.

(Keynes + Friedman) vs. Hayek
If we look at interventions government has taken to help “stimulate” the economy, the actions are more akin to the economics of Keynes and Friedman, where Congress passes stimulus packages, and the Central Bank inflates the money supply. Mainstream economics is a hybrid of the Keynes and Friedman approach. However, from Hayek’s view, the actions of a “stimulus” and inflation sow the seeds to next bust. In one respect, Friedman is a “Keynesian”, but in another he is not.

The free market usually gets associated with Friedman, but not all free market folks follow Friedman’s economics. Many free market economists follow Hayek’s vision of economics, Austrian Economics. Austrian Economics rarely uses any mathematics, but seeks to understand human action. It takes into account the human element of economics. If one is interested in understanding booms and busts from this perspective, Roger Garrison, has a slide show which depicts a model of sustainable economic growth, based on the Hayek’s Nobel Prize winning work. Also, view this music video which contrasts the Keynes versus Hayek boom-bust models.

Regardless if we disagree with the thoughts on markets, economics, or policy of Keynes, Friedman, and/or Hayek, it is interesting to note their areas of agreement, and their respective visions towards a sustainable economy.
__________
Additional Resources

Garrison, R. (1992) “Is Milton Friedman a Keynesian?” in Mark Skousen, ed., Dissent on Keynes: A Critical Appraisal of Keynesian Economics, New York: Praeger Publishers, 1992, pp. 131-147.
Garrison, R. (2002). Business Cycles: Austrian Approach . Auburn University. Retrieved March 21, 2010, from http://www.auburn.edu/~garriro/c6abc.htm
Garrison, R. (2004). From Keynes to Hayek: The Marvel of Thriving Macroeconomics.  http://www.auburn.edu/~garriro/sdae04.pdf
Garrison, R. (2007). Hayek and Friedman: Head to Head. SEA Meeting: New Orleans. Retrieved March 21, 2010, from http://www.auburn.edu/~garriro/hayek%20and%20friedman.pdf
Mariano, Jonathan (2010).  Business Cycles: Symptoms vs. Causes.  Austrian Scholars Conference 2010, Mises Institute.  Retrieved March 21, 2010, from http://jonathanmariano.blogspot.com/2010/03/business-cycle-theories-symptoms-versus.html
Papola, John (2010). Fear the Boom and Bust. EconStories.tv.  Retrieved March 21, 2010, from http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=d0nERTFo-Sk
Photo: http://www.flickr.com/photos/nickwheeleroz/3658481865/sizes/l/


Jonathan Mariano is an MBA candidate with the Presidio Graduate School in San Francisco, CA. His background ranges the spectrum from co-founding an internet startup, to leading technological change for an established nationwide home builder. His interests include the convergence between lean & green and pursuing free-market based sustainable solutions.

0 Thoughts to “Hayek Vs Keynes Compare And Contrast Essay

Leave a comment

L'indirizzo email non verrà pubblicato. I campi obbligatori sono contrassegnati *